Book Reviews

Published on May 2016 | Categories: Documents | Downloads: 41 | Comments: 0 | Views: 362
of 5
Download PDF   Embed   Report

Comments

Content

Reviews
New Age Economics
Reviewed by Jacqueline R. Kasun
ENVIRONMENTAL AND NATURAL RESOURCES ECONOMICS: Theory, Policy, and the Sustainable Society

by Steven C. Hackett
M.E. Sharpe, 1998, 327 pp.

D

eforestation, rising sea levels, greenhouse gas emissions, global warming, “the potential for catastrophic change in the global climate…inundation of…low-lying areas… desertification of…grainproducing areas…mass hunger… rapid loss of biodiversity,” threats to the “habitats of many of the world’s species of animals and plants (pp.1213), disappearance of wetlands, acid rain that “may be responsible for as many as 50,000 deaths in the United States each year” (pp. 175-6)—in horrifying detail, Steven C. Hackett describes our state of environmental collapse. But he also offers hope to the readers of his new college textbook in economics. He not only names the causes of these looming disasters but shows the way out. The immediate causes are “population growth and increases in … consumption,” “disproportionate consumption… by the rich” (p.13), capitalism (p. 243), private property (p. 26), and trade (p. 225). The ultimate causes are more philosophical—“utilitarianism,” which he attributes to religious delving into natural law and

Jacqueline R. Kasun is professor emeritus of economics at Humboldt State University, Arcata, California. She is the author of The War Against Population (Ignatius, 1988, 1999 edition forthcoming).

the nefarious influence of Jeremy Bentham, and “mainstream economics.” The way out, therefore, is to control human fecundity and to transform economics into “sustainable economics” or “ecological economics” and to adopt the biospheric vision in the spirit of deep ecology. Thus we will dedicate ourselves to “sustainable development,” which is the idyll (or idol) of the World Bank, the organizers of the 1992 “Earth Summit” in Rio de Janeiro, the UN Population Fund, the UN Environment Programme, President Clinton’s Council for Sustainable Development, and an assorted host of other contemporary world planners. Those who want to know how economics is faring these days at the college level should read this textbook. Contemporary students, of course, will not be surprised at this repetition of what they have already learned in elementary and secondary schools and from Peter Jennings and Ted Turner. Those of us who took Econ 1 in our student days and thought we learned that economics is about supply and demand in markets, however, may be in for a surprise. As for the market, it may be efficient in certain limited—very limited—circumstances but it is plagued by “market failures” (p. 40). Not only that, but it tends to “reinforce self-interested behavior” (p. 29). Indeed, students who study economics tend to be less honest and more selfish than other students (p. 28). There is no hint of Adam Smith’s perception that the market uses self-interest to induce human beings to serve one another.
Regulation

After a brief glance at John Locke, Hackett, who teaches sustainable economics at Humboldt State University in California, concludes that private property is highly suspect. “It is clear that systems centered around private property…can conflict with the common good” (p. 26), whoever decides what that is. He quotes Rousseau on its malevolent consequences: “competition and rivalry…and always the hidden desire to profit at the expense of others” (p. 26). Those who recall the arguments of Econ 1 in favor of voluntary free trade—how it must make both parties better off or they would not do it, whether they are at the swap meet or in the world rice market—will be bemused by Hackett’s denunciations. “International trade...may allow rich countries to import pollution-intensive, resource-intensive, and endangered-species products they do not wish to produce themselves and to export their toxics and trash [p. 225].” Also, “rich-country consumption is linked through the market process to serf wages and dirty production technologies in the poor countries. The process of economic growth and rising consumption has been accompanied by the evolution of multinational corporations [p. 219].” There are, nevertheless, points in favor of trade: “specialization and trade can increase the material welfare of the traders...” (p. 225). And the clincher: “As incomes increase, people have less incentive to have large families” (p. 226). Anything, even trade, to counteract “overpopulation.” We should, therefore, probably not outlaw trade altogether. But it must be strictly limited. He quotes two other enemies of trade: “Daly and Cobb argue that…free trade tends to erode livable wages, the

52

V o l u m e 22, N o . 1

bargaining power of unions, and envinightmares he envisions were upon Beyond that, they call for governronmental and other standards of us here and now, he pleads for immement controls to reduce output to communities….” Worse yet, quoting diate action. Do it now. “Preservation “sustainable biophysical limits” (p. Chichilnisky, the “ ‘tragedy of the has option value...” (p. 110) “…there 143); the resettlement of large numcommons’ ” is worsened by trade and is no good ethical argument for bers of the population in rural areas transmitted to the entire world econousing a pure rate of time preference (pp. 264, 311) (remember Pol Pot); my” (p. 226-7). other than zero...,” quoting Azar and taxes on income, land use, energy, Among the causes of the world Sterner (p. 241). consumer purchases, gifts, inherienvironmental crisis, Hackett cites Hackett’s admiring references to tance, pollution, and the extraction of the highly uneven distribution of the “deep ecology” of Herman Daly raw materials, so as to reduce both world income (p. 13), as if income and Bill Devall are worthy of note. He output and inequality (pp. 318-329); bore no relationship to productivity. describes Daly’s proposal for limiting the abolition of direct elections, But people in Calcutta, suffocating births by government-issued, transexcept for local officials, who would under their kleptocratic bureaucracy, ferable birth licenses, and he quotes in turn elect higher officers of the are not desperately poor because Devall’s call for “a substantial government (p. 177); and the prohibiAmericans are free to work and earn decrease of the human population.” tion of the movement of private comfortable incomes. “Hate the rich” (Bill Devall, Simple in Means, Rich in wealth (pp. 221, 233). messages have never helped the Ends, Salt Lake City: Peregrine Smith, After some years at the World world’s poor or the natural environ1988.) True, he only quotes other Bank, Daly now helps a like-mindment and will not now. authors, but his emphasis on the evils ed soul, Robert Costanza, direct the Also unworthy of an economist, caused by the “continued growth of International Society for Ecological he claims, after quoting Economics, which pubarguments that environlishes the journal Ecologimental cleanup causes job cal Economics, cited by “Hate the rich” messages have never loss, that “environmentalHackett (p. 209). ly friendlier technologies To combat the pernihelped the world’s poor or the natural often enhance employcious influences of mainment” (p. 11). This is true, line economics with its environment and will not now. but an economist, of all emphasis on free markets people, should underand private property and stand and teach that the individual rights and object of economic activity is not human population” (p. 12) makes his trade, Hackett suggests “the sustainmerely to keep people busy but to cremeaning clear. ability ethic,” which “holds the interate useful output. Hackett’s “keep ’em Hackett says, “Daly and Cobb... dependent health and well-being of busy” and “hate the rich” themes are illustrate the difference between the human communities and earth’s reminiscent of other world planners. mainstream of contemporary ecoecology over time as the basis of Apologists for the failed Soviet econonomic thought and the emerging susvalue” rather than “individualism” (p. my argued for years that it maintained tainability economics.” (p. 207). They 209). But, obviously, some individufull employment, without acknowldo, indeed. In their For the Common als are going to be making these value edging that it produced an abysmal Good: Redirecting the Economy towards decisions. Who? level of output along with unexcelled Community, the Environment and a SusThere is an ominous ring to these rates of pollution and environmental tainable Future (Green Print: Merlin phrases and to his promise that the destruction and an almost complete Press, 1990), the two authors call for a new system will require not only vollack of human freedom. conversion of “half or more” of the untary compliance secured through Economists usually make allowland area of the United States to “group discussion and communicaances for uncertainty and for the unsettled wilderness inhabited by tion” (p. 81) (ever hear of Chinese lapse of time when they try to estiwild animals (p. 255); a giant forced neighborhood committees?) but also mate the impact of future events reduction in trade and a change to “interventions in the form of regula(such as the yield of a mine or the self-sufficiency at not only the nationtions, taxes, subsidies, and direct possibility of “global warming”). But al level but at local levels also (pp. funding of clean technology research not Hackett. He claims that many of 229-235, 269-272); complete populaand development” (p. 277). Careful the numerous distinguished sciention control with births limited by reading of his book makes it clear that tists who dispute his doomsday scegovernment licensing to levels consisthe sustainable paradise will be under nario are in the pay of the “coal, oil, tent with a stationary or, better yet, the tight control of an enlightened and other interests” (p. 192). He declining population (pp. 244, 246); ecological elite and that the rest of us argues against the usual discounting and the abolition of private land ownwill have much less freedom and will and, as if the future environmental ership (pp. 256-259). be much poorer and less numerous
Regulation

53

V o l u m e 22, N o . 1

than we are today. As we make tofu on our solar cookers (pp. 276, 300) in our “sustainable local communities,” our leaders will jet from one international environmental conference to another, as they now do, while planning our lives. This is not to argue that “running down the natural environment” is a desirable thing. And the environmental movement itself is a sign that people throughout the world are determined that the industrial and post-

industrial ages shall not destroy Nature. With strong popular support, for example, the National Wilderness Preservation System in the United States has expanded from 9 million acres in 1964 to 104 million acres in 1994. This is an area twice as large as New England and New Jersey. But we have now a massive drive for control by a worldwide environmental elite, rationalized by intellectuals such as Steven Hackett, that threatens the bases of civilized life.



Global Warming Is Good for You
Reviewed by S. Fred Singer
THE IMPACT OF CLIMATE CHANGE ON THE UNITED STATES ECONOMY

by Robert O. Mendelsohn and James E. Neumann (editors)
(Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1999) 320 pages

T

he influence of this book on climate policy may well be more important than the influence of climate change itself on human affairs. But until one reaches the concluding chapter there is little indication of the bombshell contained in this volume involving the efforts of twenty-six economists: namely, that the economic effects of global warming are positive and beneficial rather than negative and damaging. The dust jacket and preface merely claim that the book “improves our understanding of key issues raised in the influential Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (ipcc) reports.” What an understatement! The original ipcc report, “Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change,” assembled in 1995, relied on

S. Fred Singer is professor emeritus of environmental sciences at the University of Virginia and president of the Science & Environmental Policy Project, a nonprofit policy institute in Fairfax, Virginia.

the earlier published judgments of five authors, which were based on a small set of comprehensive sectoral studies. They concluded that a doubling of the levels of atmospheric greenhouse gases would result in global damages of 1.5 to 2 percent of GDP. (Damages in the United States were estimated at 1 to 2 percent of U.S. GDP.) These early studies by Nordhaus (1991), Cline (1992), Fankhauser (1995), Tol (1995), and Titus (1992) gave total U.S. losses, in 1990 dollars, ranging from $55 billion to $140 billion, including both market and non-market effects. But the apparent agreement on a large negative effect masks widely varying sector-by-sector estimates of the losses: agriculture, $1.1 billion to $17.5 billion; energy, $1.1 billion to $10 billion; sea level damage, $5.7 billion to $12.2 billion; timber, $0.7 billion to $43.6 billion; and water resources $7 billion to $15.6 billion. Further, all of their estimates of non-market effects are uniformly negative and, in many cases, greater than market effects. The Impact of Climate Change on the United States Economy comes to strikingly different conclusions about the economic effects of global warming, even assuming a doubling of greenhouse gases leading to a warming of 2.5°C. The improved methodology of these new studies considers, among
Regulation

other things, the possibility of adaptation. The new studies also rely on natural climate experiments, by observing energy expenditures, leisure activities, etc., in towns that experience varying temperature changes. Capital-intensive sectors, such as coastal structures and timber, are modeled dynamically. The various sectoral studies were designed to be more consistent and to respond to a broader range of climate projections. And they are more comprehensive, including commercial fishing for the first time. When all is said and done, the new studies yield large positive effects for agriculture and smaller positive effects for timber and recreation. Estimates for the remaining sectors are still negative, but considerably less negative than the previous ipcc estimates. On balance, warming is found to increase U.S. gdp by about 0.2 percent. The reversal of the earlier estimates is startling, but it should not be entirely unexpected to those who have been following the economic literature of recent years. Individual research papers have indeed shown a large positive effect of warming on agriculture, arising from longer growing seasons, warmer nights, increased precipitation, and a higher level of carbon dioxide to hasten plant growth. The editors of the book were not yet aware that modest warming would retard the rise in sea level rise rather than accelerate it. That fact reinforces the clear implication of their research, which is that global warming is good for us, that is will improve our economic wellbeing as well as our health. Similar conclusions apply not only to other industrialized nations but also to the rest of the world, including island nations that fear a rising sea level. Will these new results lead politicians to blunt or even reverse the drive to limit carbon dioxide emissions and curtail energy use, or will it be politics as usual? Similarly, will the new results chasten economists who have been engaged in cost-benefit analyses of global warming—a phenomenon with positive economic effects— when the costs of mitigating it are between 1 and 2 percent of gdp?



54

V o l u m e 22, N o . 1

Reviews
Q U I C K L O O K S

by Peter VanDoren
futures contracts and options. In effect we need the housing value and labor income equivalents of the S&P 500. Professor Shiller outlines some of the technical innovations that must occur before markets will bear the risks now commonly left to government.
The Genie out of the Bottle

Macroeconomic Essentials for Media Interpretation

by Peter Kennedy
(M.I.T. Press, 1997) 384 pages

P

eter kennedy makes the dismal science of economics more accessible to the uninitiated. In a previous book, now in its third edition, he tackled the difficult task of helping undergraduates understand statistical methods in economics. In this book he attempts to do the same for macroeconomics. Fiscal and monetary policy, inflation, and economic growth are all explained in a very accessible way. Kennedy not only defines the gnp deflator and the Consumer Price Index, he also tells the reader how they are calculated and how to use them to convert prices in any particular year to current-year equivalents. If every journalist who covers the economy would read this book and Memos to the President by Charles Schultze, fewer silly things would be written.
Macro Markets: Creating Institutions for Managing Society’s Largest Economic Risks

by M. A. Adelman
(M.I.T. Press, 1995) 350 pages

P

by Robert J. Shiller
(Oxford University Press, 1993) 254 pages

rofessor adelman of m.i.t. has written the definitive economic history of the petroleum industry. Chapter 2 acquaints the reader with the fundamental economics of oil supply. The remaining chapters take us from the early days of the oil industry to the early 1990s. Professor Adelman’s writing style is refreshingly blunt, unlike the more common on-the-one-hand, onthe-other-hand prose of the two-handed economist. An example: “So-called strategic trade theory is old hat for oil. Consuming countries have invoked economies of scale and learning curves to promote domestic energy sources. They ‘pick winners’ who turn out to be losers and keep subsidizing them to maintain jobs and cover up mistakes [pp. 7-8].”

argues that the increase in tax rates on the wealthy in 1993 had fairly substantial effects on their subsequent reported income, and Nada Eissa reports that tax rates have large effects on the labor supply of married women but not on men. A paper on Medical Savings Accounts (msa) examines the persistence of medical expenses over time. msas are likely to be more successful if expenses are not correlated across years so that individuals can build up account balances. The authors find that expenses do not persist across years. David Bradford and Derek Max report that community rating of health insurance, the elimination of variance in premiums by age, would result in a one-time transfer to the currently old.
Economics of Income Redistribution

by Gordon Tullock
(Kluwer Academic Publishers, 2d edition, 1997) 222 pages

P

I

nsurance companies have long offered policies to cover risks associated with home ownership and the theft of property. But the industry has not devised policies to cover two major sources of unpleasant economic shocks: fluctuations in the value of homes and fluctuations in income earned in the labor market. Professor Shiller, an economist at Yale, argues that certain technical impediments inhibit the development of such risksharing arrangements as indices that could be the basis for the settlement of

Tax Policy and the Economy

by James M. Poterba (editor)
(M.I.T. Press, volume 10, 1996) 151 pages, (M.I.T. Press, volume 11, 1997) 211 pages

S

ince the passage of fundamental tax reform in 1986, the National Bureau of Economic Research has held an annual conference to discuss recent research relevant to tax policy. The proceedings of those conferences give excellent summaries of current policy-relevant research. In these volumes, Martin Feldstein
Regulation

rofessor tullock, long associated with James Buchanan in the “Public Choice School” of economics, has written a new edition of his classic examination of transfer programs run by governments. He writes refreshingly and does not mince words. The U.S. government spends enough on transfers to give about $20,000 to every person in the bottom 20 percent of the income distribution. Of course, very little of that money actually goes to the poor. Instead government makes large transfers to functional groups, like the aged, even if they are not poor. The bulk of transfers in the United States go to the politically influential and organized. The major motive for transfers is that the recipients of the money want it and have the political power to get it. The poor do not seem to get a very good return on their votes.

55

V o l u m e 22, N o . 1

History of the Eighties: Lessons for the Future

tors can evaluate the likelihood that banks will act in depositors’ interest.
Discrimination in Financial Services

Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation
(FDIC, 1997) 2 Volumes 572 and 118 pages

the home mortgage market is the textbook impersonal national market in which there is a standard product and no barriers to entry.
Managing Change in the Postal and Delivery Industries

I

n these two volumes the research staff of the fdic present their “official” written-by-committee version of the banking crises of the 1980s. The history is dense with facts, charts, and analyses and is thus an extremely useful source of banking industry data. Why does the fdic care about the data? Because it would like to be able to predict the likelihood of bank failures and thus prevent them and thus keep the political system content. The analysts conclude that banks that have failed shared a common characteristic: a low ratio of assets to net worth. But because other banks with similar risk characteristics did not fail, it is difficult to predict failures far in advance on the basis of risk characteristics (p. 74). A more promising line of attack is what the fdic calls the academic view: the belief that regulation is not the answer. Rather, incentives for depositors, owners, and managers should be structured to ensure that managers act in the interest of owners and depositors. And incentives should be transparent so that deposi-

by George J. Benston, W. Curt Hunter, and George W. Kaufman (editors)
(Kluwer Academic publishers, 1997) 236 pages

by Michael A. Crew and Paul R. Kleindorfer (editors)
(Kluwer Academic publishers, 1997) 424 pages

D

o banks discriminate against black mortgage applicants? Careful research by Alice Munnell suggested that even after controlling for thirty-eight measures of creditworthiness and risk, nonwhite mortgage applicants were less likely to be approved. This book, a reprint of a special issue of the Journal of Financial Services Research examines new research on this explosive issue. The book ends with three essays entitled “What Do We Know?”, “What Do We Not Know?”, and “How Should We Proceed?” These summaries very effectively capture the statistical issues as well as the policy issues. Does the statistical association between race and mortgage denial really indicate that lenders actually use race as a decision variable or is race a surrogate for omitted variables that are valid economic reasons for denial? If the market for home mortgages does not work, then no markets work because

T

his book is a collection of papers presented at the fourth biennial conference on Postal and Delivery Services, held in 1996. The papers examine economic issues at the heart of the debate about postal and delivery services. For example, it is commonly believed that postal services must be a monopoly so that profits from high-density, low-cost urban routes can subsidize high-cost rural routes. A paper by Halsi and Merewitz argues that all but the least dense rural routes are profitable at the current uniform rate (p. 239). A paper by Cote and Takis notes that the Swedish Post Office since 1993 has faced what was thought to be the worst possible scenario: a loss of the monopoly over first class service, but continuation of the obligation for universal service. Ironically, it has survived and one of its private competitors has filed for bankruptcy (p. 353).

www.socialsecurity.org
The latest research on Social Security —at your fingertips • newly redesigned • easier access • interactive calculator
The Cato Institute’s Project on Social Security Privatization Web site is an informative grass-roots lobbying tool, especially its privatization calculator. —Individual Investor





The savvy Web site from the Cato Institute proves that this libertarian think tank has its act together . . . Cato’s Web site is always one step ahead of its visitors, providing scores of research and information in a provocative way that keeps the eyes from glazing over. —Dow Jones
Y O U R M O N E Y, Y O U R C H O I C E , Y O U R F U T U R E





1000 Massachusetts Ave., N.W. • Washington, D.C. 20001 • Phone: 202-842-0200 • www.cato.org

Regulation

56

V o l u m e 22, N o . 1

Sponsor Documents

Or use your account on DocShare.tips

Hide

Forgot your password?

Or register your new account on DocShare.tips

Hide

Lost your password? Please enter your email address. You will receive a link to create a new password.

Back to log-in

Close